In a floating-rate system, it is the market forces that determine the exchange rate between two currencies. The advocates of the floating-rate system put forth two major arguments. One is that the exchange rate varies automatically according to the changes in the macro-economic variables.
In a floating-rate
system, it is the market forces that determine the exchange rate between two currencies. The advocates of
the floating-rate system put forth two major
arguments. One is that the exchange
rate varies automatically according to the changes in the macro-economic variables.
As a result,
there does not appear any gap between the real exchange rate and the nominal
exchange rate. The country does not need any adjustment that is often required in a fixed-rate regime and so it does not
have to bear the cost of adjustment (Friedman,
1953). The other is that this system possesses insulation properties
meaning that the currency
remains isolated of the shocks emanating from other countries. It also means that the government can adopt an independent economic policy without impinging
upon the external sector
performance (Friedman, 1953).
However, the
empirical studies do not necessarily confirm these views. MacDonald (1988) finds that the exchange rates among the countries on floating rate
system during 1973-85 were much more
volatile than warranted by changes in fundamental monetary variables. Dunn (1983) finds absence of insulation properties. During early 1980s, when the USA was practicing tight monetary
policy through raising interest rates, the European countries raised interest rates so as to prevent large outflow
of capital to the USA. Again, since
the nominal exchange rate tendered to adjust more rapidly than the market price
of goods, nominal exchange rate turbulence was closely
related to real exchange rate turbulence (Frenkel
and Mussa, 1980). Cushman (1983) feels that uncertainty in real exchange
rate did affect trade among
several industrialized countries. Dunn (1983) gives an example of Canadian
firms borrowing long-term
funds from the USA that faced heavy losses due to 14 percent real depreciation of Canadian
dollar during 1976-79. He also finds that large appreciation in the real value of pound in late 1970s had led to
insolvency of many UK firms as their products turned
uncompetitive in world market.
Besides,
developing countries in particular do not find floating rates suitable for them. Since their economy is not
diversified and since their export is subject to frequent changes in demand and supply, they face frequent changes in exchange
rates. This is more especially when foreign demand
for the products
is price-inelastic. When the value of their currency depreciates, export earnings usually sag in view of
inelastic demand abroad. Again,
greater flexibility in exchange rates between a developed and a developing
country generates greater exchange risk in the latter. It is
because of low economic profile of the developing
countries and also because they have limited access to forward market and to other risk-reducing mechanisms.
Floating rate
system may be independent or managed. Theoretically speaking, the system of managed floating involves
intervention by the monetary authorities of the country
for the purpose of
exchange rate stabilization. The process of intervention interferes with market forces and so it is known as “dirty” floating as against independent floating which is known as “clean” floating. However, in
practice, intervention is global phenomenon.
Keeping this fact in mind, the IMF is of the view that while the purpose
of intervention in case of independent floating system is to
moderate the rate of change, and to prevent undue fluctuation, in exchange
rate; the purpose
in managed floating
system is to establish a level for the exchange rate.
Intervention is
direct as well indirect. When the monetary authorities stabilize exchange rate through changing interest
rates, it is indirect intervention. On the other hand, in case of direct intervention, the monetary authorities
purchase and sell foreign currency in the domestic market. When
they sell foreign currency, its supply increases. The domestic
currency appreciates against the foreign currency. When they purchase foreign currency, its demand increases.
The domestic
currency tends to depreciate vis-à-vis the foreign currency. The IMF permits
such intervention. If intervention is adopted for preventing long-term changes in exchange
rate away from equilibrium, it is known as “learning-against-the-wind” intervention. Intervention helps move up
or move down the value of domestic currency also
through the expectations channel. When the monetary authorities begin
supporting the foreign currency,
speculators begin buying it forward in the expectation that it will appreciate. Its demand
rises and in turn its value appreciates vis-à-vis domestic currency.
Intervention may be stabilizing or destabilizing. Stabilizing intervention helps move the exchange rate towards equilibrium
despite intervention. The former causes gains of foreign
exchange, while the latter causes loss of foreign exchange. Suppose rupee
depreciates from 33 a dollar to 36 a dollar. The Reserve Bank sell US $ 1000 and rupee improves to 33.
The RBI will be able to replenish the lost reserves
through buying dollar at ` 33/US $.
The gain will be US $ (36000/33-1000) or US $ 91. But after intervention, if rupee falls to 40 a dollar, the loss will be US $ (36000/40-1000) or US $ 100. The monetary authorities do not normally go for destabilizing intervention, but it is
very difficult to know in advance whether
intervention would be really destabilizing. The empirical studies show both the stabilizing and
destabilizing intervention. Longworth’s study (1980 finds stabilizing intervention in case of Canadian
dollar, while Taylor
(1982) finds destabilizing intervention in case of some European
countries and Japan during 1970s.
Again,
intervention may be sterilized or non-sterilized, when the monetary authorities
purchase foreign currency through created money, the money supply in the country
increases. It leads to inflation. This is example of non-sterilized
intervention, but if simultaneously, securities are sold in the market to mop
up the excess supply of money, intervention does not lead to inflation. It
takes the form of sterilized intervention. The study of Obstfeld (1983) reveals
that non-sterilized intervention is common, for sterilized intervention is not
very effective in view of the fact that it does not change very evidently the ratio
between the supply of domestic currency and that of the foreign currency.
However, on the whole, Loopesko (1984) confirms the effect of the intervention
on the exchange rate stabilization. Last but least, there has also been a case
of co-ordinated intervention. As per the Plaza Agreement of 1985, G-5 nations
had intervened in the foreign exchange market in order to bring US dollar in
consistence with the prevailing economic indicators.