Stock prices are determined by a number of factors such as fundamental factors, technical factors and psychological factors. The behavior of stock prices is studied with the help of different methods such as fundamental analysis and technical analysis. Fundamental analysis seeks to evaluate the intrinsic value of securities by studying the fundamental factors affecting the performance of the economy, industry and companies.
Stock prices are determined by a number of
factors such as fundamental factors, technical factors and psychological
factors. The behavior of stock prices is studied with the help of different methods
such as fundamental analysis and technical analysis. Fundamental analysis seeks
to evaluate the intrinsic value of securities by studying the fundamental
factors affecting the performance of the economy, industry and companies.
Technical analysis believes that the past behavior of stock prices gives an
indication of the future behavior. It tries to study the patterns in stock
price behavior through charts and predict the future movement in prices. There
is a third theory on stock price behavior which questions the assumptions of
technical analysis.
The basic assumption in technical analysis is
that stock pie movement is quite orderly and not random. The new theory
questions this assumption. From the results of several empirical studies on
stock price movements, the advocates of the new theory assert that share price
movements are random. The new theory came to be known as Random Walk Theory
because of its principal contention that share price movements represent a
random walk rather than an orderly movement.
Random Walk Theory
Stock price behavior is explained by the theory
in the following manner. A change occurs in the price of a stock only because
of certain changes in the economy, industry or company. Information about these
changes alters the stock prices immediately and the stock moves to a new level,
either upwards or downwards, depending on the type of information. This rapid
shift to a new equilibrium level whenever new information is received is
recognition of the fact that all information which is known is fully reflected
in the price of the stock. Further change in the price of the stock will occur
only as a result of some other new piece of information which was not available
earlier. Thus, according to this theory, changes in stock prices show
independent behavior and are dependent on the new pieces of information that
are received but within themselves are independent of each other. Each price
change is independent of other price changes because each change is caused by a
new piece of information.
The basic premise in random walk theory is that
the information on changes in the economy, industry and company performance is
immediately and fully spread so that all investors have full knowledge of the
information. There is an instant adjustment in stock prices either upwards or
downwards. Thus, the current stock price fully reflects all available
information on the stock. Therefore, the price of a security two days ago can
in no way help in speculating the price two days later. The price of each day
is independent. It may be unchanged, higher or lower from the previous price,
but that depends on new pieces of information being received each day.
The random walk theory presupposes that the
stock markets are so efficient and competitive that there is immediate price
adjustment. This is the result of good communication system through which
information can be spread almost anywhere in the country instantaneously. Thus,
the random walk theory is based on the hypothesis that the stock markets are
efficient. Hence, this theory later came to be known as the efficient market
hypothesis (EMH) or the efficient market model.
The Efficient Market Hypothesis
This hypothesis states that the capital market
is efficient in processing information. An efficient capital market is one in
which security prices equal their intrinsic values at all times, and where most
securities are correctly priced. The concept of an efficient capital market has
been one of the dominant themes in academic literature since the 1960s. According
to Elton and Gruber, “when someone refers to efficient capital markets, they
mean that security prices fully reflect all available information”.’ According
to Eugene Fama,2 in an efficient market, prices fully reflect all available
information. The prices of securities observed at any time are based on correct
evaluation of all information available at that time.
The efficient market model is actually
concerned with the speed with which information is incorporated into security
prices. The technicians believe that past price sequence contains information
about the future price movements because they believe that information is
slowly incorporated in security prices. This gives technicians an opportunity
to earn excess returns by studying the patterns in price movements and trading
accordingly.
Fundamentalists believe that it may take
several days or weeks before investors can fully assess the impact of new
information. As a consequence, the price may be volatile for a number of days
before it adjusts to a new level. This provides an opportunity to the analyst
who has superior analytical skills to earn excess returns.
The efficient market theory holds the view that
in an efficient market, new information is processed and evaluated as it
arrives and prices instantaneously adjust to new and correct levels.
Consequently, an investor cannot consistently earn excess returns by
undertaking fundamental analysis or technical analysis.
Forms of Market Efficiency
The capital market is considered to be
efficient in three different forms: the weak form, semi-strong form and the
strong form. Thus, the efficient market hypothesis has been subdivided into
three forms, each dealing with a different type of information. The weak form
deals with the information regarding the past sequence of security price
movements, the semi-strong form deals with the publicly available information,
while the strong form deals with all information, both public and private (or
inside).
The different forms of efficient market
hypothesis have been tested through several empirical studies. The tests of the
weak form hypothesis are essentially tests of whether all information contained
in historical prices of securities is fully reflected in current prices.
Semi-strong form tests of the efficient market hypothesis are tests of whether
publicly available information is fully reflected in current stock prices.
Finally, strong form tests of the efficient market hypothesis are tests of
whether all information, both public and private (or inside), is fully
reflected in security prices and whether any type of investor is able to earn
excess returns.
Empirical Tests of Weak Form
Efficiency
The weak form of the efficient market
hypothesis (EMH) says that the current prices of stocks already fully reflect
all the information that is contained in the historical sequence of prices. The
new price movements are completely random. They are produced by new pieces of
information and are not related or dependent on past price movements.
Therefore, there is no benefit in studying the historical sequence of prices to
gain abnormal returns from trading in securities. This implies that technical
analysis, which relies on charts of price movements in the past, is not a
meaningful analysis for making abnormal trading profits.
The weak form of the efficient market
hypothesis is thus a direct repudiation of technical analysis.
Two approaches have been used to test the weak
form of the efficient market hy-pothesis. One approach looks for statistically
significant patterns in security price changes. The alternative approach
searches for profitable short-term trading rules.
Serial Correlation Test
Since the weak form EMH postulates independence
between successive price changes, such independence or randomness in stock
price movements can be tested by calculating the correlation between price
changes in one period and changes for the same stock in another period. The
correlation coefficient can take on a value ranging from —1 to 1; a positive
number indicates a direct relation, a negative value implies an inverse
relationship and a value close to zero implies no relationship. Thus, if
correlation coefficient is close to zero, the price changes can be considered
to be serially independent.
Run Test
The run test is another test used to test the
randomness in stock price movements. In this test, the absolute values of price
changes are ignored; oly the direction of change is considered. An increase in
price is represented by + signs. The decrease is represented by – sign. When
there is no change in prices, it is represented by ‘O’. A consecutive
sequence.of the same sign is considered as a run.
For example, the sequence + + + — — — has two
runs. In other words, a change of sign indicates a new run. The sequence — — —
+ + 0 — — — + + + + has five runs; a run of three — ‘s, followed by a run of
two + ‘s, another run of one 0, a fourth run of three — ‘s and a fifth run of
four + ‘s. In a run test, the actual number of runs observed in a series of
stock price movements is compared with the number of runs in a randomly
generated number series. If no significant differences are found, then the
security price changes are considered to be random in nature.
Filter Tests
If stock price changes are random in nature, it
would be extremely difficult to develop successful mechanical trading systems.
Filter tests have been developed as direct tests of specific mechanical trading
strategies to examine their validity and usefulness.
It is often believed that, as long as no new
information enters the market, the price fluctuates randomly within two
barriers—one lower, and the other higher—around the fair price. When new
information comes into the market, a new equilibrium price will be determined.
If the news is favorable, then the price should move up to a new equilibrium
above the old price. Investors will know that this is occurring when the price
breaks through the old barrier. If investors purchase at this point, they will
benefit from the price increase to the new equilibrium level.
Likewise, if the news received is unfavorable,
the price of the stock will decline to a lower equilibrium level. If investors
sell the stock as it breaks the lower barrier, they will avoid much of the
decline. Technicians set up trading strategies based on such patterns to earn excess
returns.
The strategy is called a filter rule. The
filter rule is usually stated in the following way: Purchase the stock when it
rises by x per cent from the previous low and sell it when it declines by x per
cent from the subsequent high. The filters may range from 1 per cent to 50 per
cent or more. The alternative to this active trading strategy is the passive
buy and hold strategy.
The returns generated by trading according to
the filter rule are compared with the returns earned by an investor following
the buy and hold strategy. If trading with filters results in superior returns
that would suggest the existence of patterns in price movements and negate the
weak form EMH.
Distribution Pattern
It is a rule of statistics that the
distribution of random occurrences will conform to a normal distribution. Then,
if price changes are random, their distribution should also be approximately
normal. Therefore, the distribution of price changes can be studied to test the
randomness or otherwise of stock price movements.
In the 1960s the efficient market theory was
known as the random walk theory. The empirical studies regarding share price
movements were testing whether prices followed a random walk.
Two articles by Roberts and Osborne, both
published in 1959, stimulated a great deal of discussion of the new theory then
called random walk theory.
Roberts’ study compared the movements in the
Dow Jones Industrial Average (an American stock market index) with the movement
of a variable generated from a random walk process. He found that the random
walk process produced patterns which were very similar to those of the Dow
Jones index.
Osborne’s study found a close resemblance
between share price changes and the random movement of small particles
suspended in a solution, which is known in Physics as the Brownian motion. Both
the studies suggested that share price changes are random in nature and that
past prices had no predictive value.
During the 1960s there was an enormous growth
in serial correlation testing. None of these found any substantial linear
dependence in price changes. Studies by Moore, Fama and Hagerman and Richmond
are some of the early studies in this area. Moore found an average serial
correlation coefficient of — 0.06 for price changes measured over weekly
intervals. Fama’s study tested the serial correlation for the thirty stocks
comprising the Dow Jones industrial average for the five years prior to 1962.
The average serial correlation coefficient was found to be 0.03. Both the
coefficients were not statistically different from zero; thus both the studies
supported the random walk theory.
Fama also used run tests to measure dependency.
The results again supported the random walk theory. Many studies followed
Moore’s and Fama’s work each of which used different databases. The results of
these studies were much the same as those of Moore and Fama.
Hagerman and Richmond conducted similar studies
on securities traded in the ‘over- the-counter’ market and found little serial
correlation. Serial correlation tests of dependence have also been carried out
in various other stock markets around the world. These have similarly revealed
little or no serial correlation.
Much research has also been directed towards
testing whether mechanical trading strategies are able to earn above average
returns. Many studies have tested the filter rules for its ability to earn
superior returns. Early American studies were those by Alexander, who
originally advocated the filter strategy, and by Fama and Blume. There were similar
studies in the United Kingdom by Dryden and in Australia by Praetz. All these
studies have found that filter strategies did not achieve above average
returns. Thus, the results of empirical studies have been virtually unanimous
in finding little or no statistical dependence and price patterns and this has
corroborated the weak form efficient market hypothesis
Empirical Tests of
Semi-Strong Form Efficiency
The semi-strong form of the efficient market
hypothesis says that current prices of stocks not only reflect all
informational content of historical prices, but also reflect all publicly
available information about the company being studied. Examples of publicly
available information are—corporate annual reports, company announcements,
press releases, announcements of forthcoming dividends, stock splits, etc. The
semi-strong hypothesis maintains that as soon as the information becomes public
the stock prices change and absorb the full information. In other words, stock
prices instantaneously adjust to the information that is received.
The implication of semi-strong hypothesis is
that fundamental analysts cannot make superior gains by undertaking fundamental
analysis because stock prices adjust to new pieces of information as soon as
they are received. There is no time gap in which a fundamental analyst can
trade for superior gains. Thus, the semi-strong hypothesis repudiates
fundamental analysis.
Semi-strong form tests deal with whether or not
security prices fully reflect all publicly available information. These tests
attempt to establish whether share prices react precisely and quickly to new
items of information. If prices do not react quickly and adequately, then an
opportunity exists for investors or analysts to earn excess returns by using
this information. Therefore, these tests also attempt to find if analysts are
able to earn superior returns by using publicly available information.
There is an enormous amount and variety of
public information. Semi-strong form tests have been performed with respect to
many different types of information. Much of the methodology used in
semi-strong form tests has been introduced by Fama, Fisher, Jensen and Roll.
Theirs was the first of the studies that were directly concerned with the
testing of the semi-strong form of EMH. Subsequent to their study, a number of
refinements have been developed in the test procedure.
The general methodology followed in these
studies has been to take an economic event and measure its impact on the share
price. The impact is measured by taking the difference between the actual
return and expected return on a security. The expected return on a security is
generally estimated by using the market model (or single index model) suggested
by William Sharpe. The model used for estimating expected returns is the
following:
Ri= ai + biRm + ei
Where
This analysis is known as Residual analysis.
The positive difference between the actual return and the expected return
represents the excess return earned on a security. If the excess return is
close to zero, it implies that the price reaction following the public
announcement of information is immediate and the price adjusts to a new level
almost immediately. Thus, the lack of excess returns would validate the semi-strong
form EMH.
Major studies on the impact of capitalization
issues such as stock splits and stock dividends have been conducted in the
United States by Fama, Fisher, Jensen and Roll and Johnson, in Canada by Finn,
and in the United Kingdom by Firth. All these studies found that the market
adjusted share prices instantaneously and accurately for the new information.
Both Pettit and Watts have investigated the market’s reaction to dividend
announcements. They both found that all the price adjustment was over
immediately after the announcement and thus, the market had acted quickly in
evaluating the information.
Other items of information whose impact on
share prices have been tested include announcements of purchase and sale of
large blocks of shares of a company, takeovers, annual earnings of companies,
quarterly earnings, accounting procedure changes, and earnings estimates made
by company officials. All these studies which made use of the Residual analysis
approach, showed the market to be relatively efficient.
Ball and Brown tested the stock market’s
ability to absorb the informational content of reported annual earnings per
share information. They found that companies with good earnings report
experienced price increase in stock, while companies with bad earnings report
experienced decline in stock prices. But surprisingly, about 85 per cent of the
informational content of the earnings announcements was reflected in stock
price movements prior to the release of the actual earnings figure. The market seems
to adjust to new information rapidly with much of the impact taking place in
anticipation of the announcement.
Joy, Litzenberger and McEnally tested the
impact of quarterly earnings announcements on the stock price adjustment
mechanism. Some of their results, however, contradicted the semi-strong form of
the efficient market hypothesis. They found that the favorable information
contained in published quarterly earnings reports was not always
instantaneously adjusted in stock prices. This may suggest that the market does
not adjust share prices equally well for all types of information.
By way of summary it may be stated that a great
majority of the semi- strong efficiency tests provide strong empirical support
for the hypothesis; however, there have been some contradictory results too.
Most of the reported results show that stock prices do adjust rapidly to
announcements of new information and that investors are typically unable to
utilize this information to earn consistently above average returns.
Tests of Strong Form Efficiency
The strong form hypothesis represents the
extreme case of market efficiency. The strong form of the efficient market
hypothesis maintains that the current security prices reflect all information
both publicly available information as well as private or inside information.
This implies that no information, whether public or inside, can be used to earn
superior returns consistently.
The directors of companies and other persons
occupying senior management positions within companies have access to much
information that is not available to the general public. This is known as
inside information. Mutual funds and other professional analysts who have large
research facilities may gather much private information regarding different stocks
on their own. These are private information not available to the investing
public at large.
The strong form efficiency tests involve two
types of tests. The first type of tests attempt to find whether those who have
access to inside information have been able to utilize profitably such inside
information to earn excess returns. The second type of tests examine the
performance of mutual funds and the recommendations of investment analysts to
see if these have succeeded in achieving superior returns with the use of
private information generated by them.
Jaffe, Lorie and Niederhoffer studied the
profitability of insider trading (i.e. the investment activities of people who
had inside information on companies). They found that insiders earned returns
in excess of expected returns. Although there have been only a few empirical
studies on the profitability of using inside information, the results show, as
expected, that excess returns can be made. These results indicate that markets
are probably not efficient in the strong form.
Many studies have been carried out regarding
the performance of American mutual funds using fairly sophisticated evaluation
models. All the major studies have found that mutual funds did no better than
randomly constructed portfolios of similar risk. Firth studied the performance
of Unit Trusts in the United Kingdom during the period 1965—75. He also found
that unit trusts did not outperform the market index for their given levels of
risk. A small research has been conducted into the profitability of investment
recommendations by investment analysts. Such studies suggest that few analysts
or firms of advisers can claim above average success with their forecasts.
The results of research on strong form EMH may
be summarized as follows:
Inside information can be used to earn above
average returns.
Mutual funds and investment analysts have not
been able to earn superior returns by using their private information.
In conclusion, it may be stated that the strong
form hypothesis is invalid as regards inside information, but valid as regards
private information other than inside information.
EMH Vs. Fundamental and Technical Analyses
There are three broad theories concerning stock
price movements. These are the fundamental analysis, technical analysis and
efficient market hypothesis. Fundamental analysts believe that by analyzing key
economic and financial variables they can estimate the intrinsic worth of a
security and then determine what investment action to take. Fundamental
analysis seeks to identify under priced securities and overpriced securities.
Their investment strategy consists in buying under priced securities and
selling overpriced securities, thereby earning superior returns.
A technical analyst maintains that fundamental
analysis is unnecessary. He believes that history repeats itself. Hence, he
tries to predict future movements in share prices by studying the historical
patterns in share price movements.
The efficient market hypothesis is expressed in
three forms. The weak form of the EMH directly contradicts technical analysis
by maintaining that past prices and past price changes cannot be used to
forecast future price changes because successive price changes are independent
of each other. The semi-strong form of the EMH contradicts fundamental analysis
to some extent by claiming that the market is efficient in the dissemination
and processing of information and hence, publicly available information cannot
be used consistently to earn superior investment returns.
The strong form of the EMH maintains that not
only is publicly available information useless to the investor or analyst but
all information is useless.
Even though the EMH repudiates both fundamental
analysis and technical analysis, the market is efficient precisely because of
the organized and systematic efforts of thousands of analysts undertaking
fundamental and technical analysis. Thus, the paradox of efficient market
hypothesis is that both fundamental and technical analyses are required to make
the market efficient and thereby validate the hypothesis.
Competitive Market Hypothesis
An efficient market has been defined as one
where share prices always fully reflect available information on companies. In
practice, no existing stock market is perfectly efficient. There are evident
shortcomings in the pricing mechanism. Often, the complete body of knowledge
about a company’s prospects is not publicly available to market participants.
Further, the available information would not be always interpreted in a
completely accurate fashion. The research studies on EMH have shown that price
changes are random or independent and hence unpredictable. The prices are also
seen to adjust quickly to new information. Whether the price adjustments are
correct and accurate, reflecting correctly and accurately the meaning of
publicly available information is difficult to determine.
All that can be validly concluded is that
prices are set in a very competitive market, but not necessarily in an
efficient market. This competitive market hypothesis provides scope for earning
superior returns by undertaking security analysis and following portfolio
management strategies.
Market Inefficiencies
Many studies have proved the prevalence of the
market efficiency. At the same time, several studies contradict the concept of
market efficiency. For example, the studies conducted Joy, Lichtenberger and
Mc. Enally over the period of 1963-1968 gave different results. The authors
have examined the quarterly earnings of the stock prices. The earning of one
quarter was compared with the same quarter of the previous year. If the current
year’s earnings were 40% or more than the earnings for the same quarter in the
previous year, the earnings were classified as good earnings than anticipated.
If the current quarter’s earnings were below 40% of the previous year’s
earnings, they are classified as bad than expected.
Then the abnormal returns were calculated from
13 weeks prior to the announcement of the earnings to 26 weeks after the
announcement of the earnings. The stocks whose earn-ings are substantially
greater than anticipated gave positive abnormal returns. The stocks whose
earnings are below the anticipated earnings generated negative abnormal
returns.
The author’s main claim is that after the
announcement of the earnings, stocks that reported earnings substantially above
those of the previous year continued to earn positive abnormal returns.
According to the study, the investors could have earned positive abnormal
returns of around 6.5 per cent over the next 26 weeks simply by buying stocks
that have reported earnings 40% above the previous quarterly earnings.
Meanwhile for those stocks with earnings substantially below the previous year,
the cumulative average abnormal return remained relatively stable. This shows
evidence against the semi-strong market hypothesis because it states that when
the information is made public the analyst could not earn abnormal profits. A
study made by C.P. Jones, R. S. Randleman for the period 1971-1980 had also
given similar results to those of JLM.
Low PE effect many studies have provided
evidences that stocks with low price earnings ratios yield higher returns than
stocks with higher PEs. This is known as low PE effect. A study made by Basu in
1977 was risk adjusted return and even after the adjustment there was excess
return in the low price-earnings stocks. If historical information of P/E
ratios is useful to the investor in obtaining superior stock returns, the
validity of the semi-strong form of market hypothesis is questioned. His results
stated that low P/E portfolio experienced superior returns relative to the
market and high P/E portfolio performed in an inferior manner relative to the
overall market. Since his result directly contradicts semi-strong form of
efficient market hypothesis, it is considered to be important.
Small firm effect the theory of the small firm
effect maintains that investing in small firms (those with low capitalization)
provides superior risk adjusted returns. Bans found that the size of the firm
has been highly correlated with returns. Bans examined historical monthly
returns of NYSE common stocks for the period 1931-1975. He formed portfolios
consisting of 10 smallest firms and the 10 largest firms and computed the
average return for these portfolios. The small firm portfolio has outperformed
the large firm portfolio.
Several other studies have confirmed the
existence of a small firm effect. The size effect has given rise to the doubts
regarding the risk associated with small firms. The risk associated with them
is underestimated and they do not trade as frequently as the those of the large
firms. Correct measurement of risk and return of small portfolios tends to
eliminate at least 50% of the small firm effect.
The weekend effect French in his study had
examined the returns generated by the Standard and poor Index for each day of
the week. Stock prices tend to rise all week long to a peak on Fridays. The
stocks are traded on Monday at reduced prices, before they begin the next
week’s price rise. Buying on Monday and selling on Friday from 1953 to 1977
would have generated average annual return 3.4% while simple buy and hold would
have yielded 5.5% annual return. If the transaction costs are taken into
account, the naive buy and hold strategy would have provided higher return. Yet
the knowledge of the weekend effect is still of v Purchases planned on Thursday
or Friday can be delayed until Monday, while sale planned for Monday can b
delayed until the end of the week. The weekend effect is a small but significant
deviation from perfectly random price movements and violates the weekly
efficient market hypothesis.
Similar to this Venkatesh B. of the BL Research
Bureau has stated that the Bombay Stock Exchange reveal a discernible pattern.
Usually, Monday, is characterized by trading blues, and Friday by frenzied
activity The Friday rush is more to do with speculators covering their open
position. If the short sellers to cover their position within this period,
their open positions are called to auction where prices are dear.
Summary
The technical analysts studies the behaviour of
the price of the stock to determine the future price of the –stock
According to Charles H. Dow, stock price
movements are divided into three: the primary movement, the secondary movement
and the daily fluctuations.
A primary trend may be a bull market moving in
a steady upward direction, or a bear market steadily dropping.
A secondary trend or secondary reaction is the
movement of the market contrary to the primary trend.
Support level is the barrier for further
decline. It provides a base for an up move. The resistance level is the level
in which advances are temporarily stopped and the sellers overcome the demand.
Volume of the trade confirms the trend. Fall of
volume with the rise in price indicates trend reversal and vice-versa.
Breadth of the market is the net number of
stocks advancing versus, those declining in the market. If the Al D line slopes
downward while the Sensex is rising, it gives a bearish signal and vice-versa.
Moving averages are used as a technical
indicator. It smoothens out the short term fluctuations, helpful in comparing
the stock price movement with the index movement and discovering the trend.